SIAM News Blog
SIAM News
Print

Mathematically Addressing Optimal Public Debt

By Karthika Swamy Cohen

While most countries around the world rely on debt to finance their government and economy, keeping this debt under control is a financial imperative. Large government debt negatively impacts long-term economic growth.  Increase in a nation’s debt results in lower private investment, which leads to diminishing growth and wages in the long term. A high amount of debt can be detrimental even in the absence of a financial crisis.

Large government debt negatively impacts long-term economic growth. Public domain image.
“There is a huge debate in the economic and political community on the sustainability of public debt,” observes Giorgio Ferrari, a professor for mathematical finance at Universität Bielefeld in Germany, and principal investigator in the Collaborative Research Centre 1283. “Using different statistical and methodological approaches, many researchers conclude that high government debt has a negative effect on long-term economic growth, makes the economy less resilient to macroeconomic shocks, and poses limits on the adoption of counter-cyclical fiscal policies.”

The debt-to-gross domestic product (GDP) ratio is an important indicator of an economy’s financial leverage. “During the last financial crisis, the debt-to-GDP ratio—also called debt ratio—exploded in many countries,” says Ferrari, who proposes a mathematical model for the control of this ratio in a paper publishing today in the SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization.

To minimize the total expected cost of owing debt and implementing interventions on the debt ratio, governments choose appropriate debt reduction policies, though these are not always designed for maximum efficiency. “It is unclear if governments plan their debt reduction policies according to an optimization criterion, such as the maximization of social welfare or the minimization of social costs,” Ferrari says. “In this sense, mathematical modeling can provide a theoretical background for such choices, and might give insights on the policies to follow.”

Ferrari models the problem as a continuous singular stochastic control problem, and tries to answer the question, “How much is too much?” — as in, at what level of debt does it help for the government to pay back without impacting growth? For many developed nations, whose debt-to-GDP ratio is far from risk of default, the cost of raising taxes or reducing spending to decrease debt can outweigh any benefits.

“In my model, governments face two opposing costs,” Ferrari explains. “On the one hand, they aim to minimize the total expected opportunity cost due to debt. This may result, for instance, from private investment crowding out public investments, leaving less room for public ventures, and from a tendency to suffer low subsequent growth. On the other hand, by reducing the debt through, say, fiscal policies, the government incurs a cost that is proportional to the amplitude of its action. It is important for governments to properly counterbalance these two costs, and such a problem can be modeled mathematically through a so-called singular stochastic control problem.”

While high debt-to-GDP ratios can restrict economic progress by augmenting the debt burden, government intervention strategies also carry penalties proportional to the amount of debt mitigation. Thus the ideal goal is to choose a cumulative debt reduction policy that would limit the total expected cost of shouldering debt and overall cost of interventions.

“A government’s need to counterbalance the cost of having debt and reducing it suggests that it should follow a threshold strategy — that is, it should intervene so as to reduce debt-to-GDP ratio only when the latter is sufficiently large,” Ferrari points out. “In my model, in its planning, the government also takes into account the current level of inflation in the country, which is not under the government's control, but managed by an autonomous central bank. As a result, the critical level at which the government should act in order to halt the growth of public debt is inflation-dependent, and this optimal threshold is endogenously determined as part of the solution to the problem.”

Graph depicting the debt-to-gross domestic product (GDP) ratio from 1875 to 2011. Public domain image.

Assuming that the government can reduce the level of debt versus the GDP by certain measures—such as raising taxes or reducing expenses—Ferrari’s group interprets the collective interventions on the debt ratio as the government’s control variable. Uncertainty in the model is introduced via the inflation of the given country.

“Clearly, in reality, when managing the public debt, the government should also consider macroeconomic variables other than inflation, for instance, interest rates, GDP growth rate, and exchange rates,” Ferrari says. “However, in order to have a tractable mathematical problem, I have decided to focus only on the role of inflation in the debt's reduction problem faced by the government.”

Ferrari shows that it is optimal for a government to adopt policies that keep the debt-to-GDP ratio under an inflation-dependent ceiling. In his work, he demonstrates that the solution of the control problem is related to that of an auxiliary optimal stopping problem developed in terms of the marginal cost of having debt and the marginal cost of intervention on the debt ratio. In the optimal stopping problem, the government determines the optimal time to reduce the debt ratio level by one additional unit with the goal of minimizing the associated total expected marginal cost. Solving the optimal stopping problem can then effectively solve the control problem.

Future research involves approaches to alleviate debt with limited data and factors beyond the government’s control. “With collaborators, my research group at the Center for Mathematical Economics at Bielefeld University is currently trying to investigate how strategic issues might enter into the picture, how a government can optimally reduce the debt ratio when it only has partial information about the involved macroeconomic quantities, or can optimally increase or decrease the debt level when the interest rate on debt is stochastic and is affected by economic shocks that are not under its control.”

Mathematical models designed to represent real-world financial situations can be both mathematically fascinating and remarkably practical. “I find problems of optimal management of macroeconomic quantities—like public debt, inflation, or exchange rates—very interesting both from an everyday-life and a mathematical perspective,” Ferrari says. “They lead to very challenging mathematical problems in which one needs to consider the interaction between several variables, including macroeconomic and financial quantities and multiple agents, such as government, central banks, and financial agents. I believe that there is still a lot to do in the mathematical analysis/modeling of such problems.”

Source article: Ferrari, G. (2018). On the Optimal Management of Public Debt: a Singular Stochastic Control ProblemSIAM J. Control Optim., 56(3), 2036-2073.

   Karthika Swamy Cohen is the managing editor of SIAM News.
blog comments powered by Disqus